From an
economic perspective, the question of who owns the tools of production--land
and capital (factories, machinery and other productive resources) is a very
important one. In a totally free market system, these are owned exclusively by
the private sector (individuals and companies); in the other
extreme--communism-- they are owned by society in common --as represented by
government. Private ownership and free enterprise are intrinsically linked. For
individuals to operate in a market economy, they need to be able to possess
their own property. Of course, in practice, the choice is not a clear one between
private and common property. The issue is, how much property should government
own?—part and parcel of the free enterprise versus socialism debate.
The
issue--private versus public (government-owned) property--has been
controversial among Christians as well. Some, for example, have claimed a
strong biblical mandate for private property, for instance, that
"private property is a Divine providence"–everyone must,
therefore, own property. On the other hand, others use the reference in the
story of Annanias and Saphira in Acts 4:32 that "no one claimed that any
of his possessions was his own but they shared everything they had" as an
indication that the Bible requires us to "hold all property in
common" and, therefore, requires government to own all.
God is Owner:-Neither position is, however,
biblically supportable. Rather, the basic thrust of Biblical teaching about
property is the stewardship principle--the mandate that the "earth is the
Lord's and everything in it (Ps 24:1)." God is the "absolute
Owner" of everything so that the rights of the human owner are, in
principle, of a limited character. That thrust is accepted by many Christian
economic authors. Chewning , for instance, stresses that God is the Owner
(Gen 25:23; Ps 24:1) and man holds all property as His steward with
"appropriate obligations and granted rights."[i]
The Dutch
theologian J.Douma has provided an extensive analysis of biblical proofs and
historic Christian views concerning ownership. He concluded that man is steward
under God, who remains absolute Owner. Both Old and New Testament indicate that
private ownership is permitted. There is no evidence, however, that we all must
have private property: "Differences in ownership are nowhere condemned;
communal ownership, centrally controlled, is nowhere commanded."[ii]
But, the Bible does make clear that personal money and property should be used
for the benefit of others.
Private Ownership
Assumed-Not Mandated:-That the Bible accepts or assumes private ownership, as such, is also
supported--among others, by Grudem, and Griffiths[iii]
The Eighth Commandment "You shall
not steal" is generally recognized as biblical protection of such private
ownership. Removing the landmarks that establish property boundaries was
expressly forbidden (Deut 19:14, 27:17). The fact that God gave Israel the
promised land and allotted to each family group according to size can certainly
be seen as God’s material blessing on his people[iv]
and an indication that private property is understood to be the normal pattern.
From the underlying theme from the Old Testament land distribution, we can also
derive the need to search for “effective structures...that will enable every family
to have the basic capital needed to earn a living.”[v]
It would go too far, however, to take this Old Testament distribution to Israel
as a mandatory pattern for us at this time.[vi]
The
contrary contention that the Bible rejects all private property has been
adequately demolished by these and many other authors.[vii]
Neither private or public ownership is specifically scripturally mandated or
rejected. As Chewning concludes,
Scripture
must...not be forced to answer questions that are culturally foreign to it...One
cannot automatically extrapolate from the property arrangements of an agrarian
and tribal culture the specifics that should be applied to a complex modern
arrangement.[viii]
Those who
argue for a biblical mandate for private property also point to the
division of the land in Israel and the protection of these inheritances through
the Jubilee laws. That is, it is argued that since God ordained that the
Israelites must all have their own land, we also must all have our own land or
private property. As Douma has shown, however, "these laws, intended as
they had been for the old covenant people in the land of Canaan" have
"no validity as integral legislation for Christians in other lands."[ix]
To take these Old Testament laws as meaning that God requires us to have
private property is, therefore, unwarranted.
Proponents
of absolute private property rights also point to Acts 4 and 5 where Peter
tells Ananias, "didn't it belong to you before it was sold, wasn't the
money at your disposal?" However, socialists use the same passage by
pointing to 4:32: "no one claimed that any of his possessions was his own
but they shared everything they had." While they are wrong to interpret
this to mean that be Bible requires us to "hold all property in
common," it would be equally wrong to use this narrative to say that the
Bible requires individual property holdings. In sum, the exaggerated
claim that private property is required or a matter of divine providence should
be rejected.
The Theft Fallacy:-Yet various Christians do, in fact,
claim that the Bible provides much more definite guidance than the relatively
limited conclusions presented above. Of particular concern is the view of
Beisner and others[x]
that the Eighth Commandment's prohibition against theft mandates unlimited
private property rights which can also not be encroached upon–even by the
government-- for instance, through taxation to assist the poor. Now, in
opposition to Beisner's claim that if the government were excluded from this
commandment, the Bible would have said so, McKinney argues that "If
individual property rights were absolute, the Eighth Commandment would
[explicitly] forbid the state's taking of income or property away from an
individual for the common good."[xi]
While that claim is also speculative, it does indicate the weakness of
Beisner's claim. McKinney does point to God's ownership of everything and the
distribution of the third-year tithe to the "Levite, the alien, the
fatherless and the widow" and concludes:
Given God's
concern for the poor, is it inconceivable that society, through the state,
could legitimately redistribute some of this property to alleviate the plight
of the poor? I think not.
The
stewardship principle is also used by Hay to argue against absolute property
rights. He observes that,
these rights
are not those of Roman law, which imply 'unconditional and exclusive use of the
property by the individual'. They are rights which impose duties and
obligations in the sense of stewardship.[xii]
Given those
obligations, is it not legitimate that the government as God's servant should
place limits on an individual's use of private property? It would certainly
seem that the Bible contains no prohibition against such limitation.
Conclusion:-In any
case, we can conclude that the Bible teaches directly only that:
1. All property belongs to God; we hold it as
stewards on His behalf; we must use it to His glory, in His service.
2. The Bible does not require or forbid either
private or public ownership of property.
3. Private
ownership, where it exists, must be protected.
Tragedy of the Commons: I do believe, however, that it
does appear possible to derive a biblically inspired preference for private ownership
which I hope to deal with in the future. I conclude this posting with a note
on, what economists refer to as the “tragedy of the commons” as an illustration
that holding property “in common” is unstewardly. The term derives from the old
English custom of holding some grazing land in common—everyone could graze his
cattle there. With everyone entitled to use the grass, the incentive for all to
let their cows or sheep graze there as soon and as long as possible. "If my cows
don’t get it now, someone else’s will!" Instead, of orderly rotating the use of
the field in order to allow the grass to regrow, all users are motivated to let
it be “grazed to death”. Another example
of this tragedy is the demise of the American buffalo. Since no one owned the
herds, all hunters took as many as they could get without worrying about the
sustainability of the herds.
Ownership
in common means, in reality, that no one manages the property on a stewardly
basis. Private ownership encourages careful management!
[i]
Richard C.
Chewning, ed., Biblical Principles
& Economics: The Foundations,
Christians in the Marketplace Series, Vol. 2, Navpress, Colorado Springs, 1989,
p.117. Similar points of
departure are found in Griffiths Morality and the Market-Place, Hodder
& Stoughton, London, 1989 (Originally 1982), p.82 Donald A. Hay, Economics Today: A Christian
Critique, Eerdmans, Grand Rapids, 1990, p.151and many others. See my book
p. 183ff.
[ii]
J. Douma, Vrede in de Maatschappij
[Peace in Society], Gereformeerd Maatschappelijk Verbond, Zwolle, 1985, Ch. 4.
See also his The Ten Commandments: Manual for the Christian Life, P
&R Publishing, Phillipsburg, N.J., 1996 (translation Nelson D.
Kloosterman), pp.297ff.
[iii]
Griffiths, The
Creation of Wealth, Hodder & Stoughton, London, 1984, p.56 and 1989, op. cit., P.92.
[iv]
Blomberg, op.
cit., p.40.
[v]
Sider, 2005,
p.74
[vi]
Chewning, Vol.
2, p.130
[vii]
See Brown in
Chewning, Vol. 2, Ch.6, E. Calvin Beisner, Prosperity and Poverty: The
Compassionate Use of Resources in a World of Scarcity, Crossway, Westchester,
1988, Ch.5, John R. Schneider, The
Good of Affluence: seeking God in a Culture of Wealth, Eerdmans, 2002,
p.195ff. and Blomberg, op. cit.,p.163ff
[viii]
Vol.2, p.61.
[ix]
J. Douma, Christian
Morals and Ethics, translation by John P. Elliott and Andrew Pol, Premier,
Winnipeg, 1980, p.28. Of course, they still have meaning for us. He says we
have to seek out the substance, the
essence of these laws, e.g., "God wanted to impress upon His people that He
not only had an eye for man and his social relations but also for land and
animals". It is worth noting that the jubilee laws applied only to
agricultural lands not to town houses and other property. It would be,
therefore, be a further unwarranted extension to apply them to all private
property as we now know it.
[x]
See McKinney
in Chewning, Vol.2, Ch. 11. Pointing to Beisner as a "forceful statement
of this view," he lists other writers espousing this view as Gary North, An
Introduction to Christian Economics, Nutley, N.J., Craig Press 1973; David
Chilton, Productive Christians in an Age of Guilt Manipulators, Tyler,
Tex., Institute for Christian Economics, 1981; Ronald H. Nash, Social
Justice and the Christian Church, (Milford, Mich, Mott, 1983, Poverty
and Wealth, Westchester, Ill, Crossway, 1986. See also Harold Lindsell, Free
Enterprise- A Judeo-Christian Defense, Tyndale, 1982 and John Jefferson
Davis, Your Wealth in God's World, Presbyterian and Reformed Publishing
House, 1984, p.80.
[xi]
In Chewning,
Vol. 2, p.235
[xii]
Op. cit.,
p.78, where he responds to Griffiths who also uses the prohibition against
theft to justify property rights
1 comment:
As usual your comments are welcomed. If you have learned something, please share with your friends.
Post a Comment